ext_48536 (
peristaltor.livejournal.com) wrote in
talkpolitics2012-02-14 05:04 pm
![[identity profile]](https://www.dreamwidth.org/img/silk/identity/openid.png)
![[community profile]](https://www.dreamwidth.org/img/silk/identity/community.png)
Entry tags:
A Corrective on The Nature of Money
I just got through reading a very insightful reply from
montecristo, one free of bombast and flourish, but focusing rather on the meat of his philosophy, a kind of exegesis. I thank him for his candor.
I cannot, though, overlook his errors. Now, before everyone rushes to the mods and reports this as a trolling post, bear in mind that he makes some very common mistakes on a subject that very few command well at all, myself especially. These mistakes are, in my opinion, directly responsible for a majority of the economic problems we are facing as a planet. Therefore, be your philosophical bent to the center, to the left, to the right; be it up to the totalitarian or down toward the anarchists; be it with Xenu or Gaia or whomever; all of us can benefit from a basic primer into the basic manner in which money today is created.
First of all, the commonly held idea. I get this from Yves Smith, an excellent money and finance blogger at Naked Capitalism. Ms. Smith spent 25 years as a banker. Let's see what she has to say about money.
Does that sound right? It does to most. The problem lies in some basic systemic realities. If banks hold deposits and lend at interest, where does the money to pay the interest come from? In other words, what mechanism creates the interest money added to the principal due at the close of the loan, or for that matter the depositor's interest on their savings and the bank's profits? Let's cut right to this chase. (From hereon, all emboldened words in those quoted will be my emphasis.) The Chicago Federal Reserve came out with a handy explanatory pamphlet once, which contained:
"Credits to the borrowers' transaction account" is what most of us would call "money." Ellen Hodgson Brown maintains the banker-esque vocabulary to clarify:
What Ms. Brown is trying to say is more clearly said by other authors, thankfully.
But what of those deposits Yves Smith mentioned earlier?
The dual role to which Mr. Greco refers is regulated by the "fractional reserve." Back to Mr. Jackson:
I hate to pick on otherwise excellent thinkers like Yves Smith, if only because her book EConned was (other than that quote above and a few minor quibbles) so enlightening. How could she not know of the loan creation of money? Yes, she spent 25 years as a banker; but it was as an investment banker. Investment banks are not allowed to create money through lending; only commercial or depository banks are. This is, in fact, the "firewall" in our financial system erected in the US by the Banking Act of 1933, aka the Glass–Steagall Act. Senators Glass and Steagall based this legislation on revelations into banking practice largely brought to light during the congressional hearings following the market crashes between 1929 and 1932, hearings conducted largely by Ferdinand Pecora. I've read half of the Stock Exchange Practices. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency Pursuant to S.Res. 84 and S.Res. 56 and S.Res. 97, aka the Pecora Commission Report. Once one has a background into the loaning of money into existence, it's relatively easy to pick through the banker banter and decipher the actual meaning of some of the more dangerous practices the Glass-Steagall Act prevented.
That Act, though, was largely repealed in 1999 by the Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act of 1999. It took a non-investment banker to predict what might — did — happen afterward.
"The level of bank lending that makes sense for individual banks" is simply the level of lending that banks can issue at interest with the most likely chance either of return . . . or of possibility to seize valuable assets obtained after default. That last is what many enamored of the gold standard don't realize, that the same system of money creation through lending was in place at that time. When the availability of gold got low, bankers simply called in their loans to be payable only in gold and waited for the defaults to lower the credit money supply. This correction hardly cost them much, since the farms and factories they repossessed more than made up for the paper losses. But I digress.
I'll return to Greco to outline the fallout of improper lending.
"Finance market speculation" was exactly the lending the Glass-Steagall Act outlawed . . . until its slow erosion starting in about 1983 and eventual repeal.
Several have warned through history of this conflict of interest banks represent. Sadly, not enough do. Worse, few realize that commodity banks are legally allowed to create money almost by fiat, money that can be used to further gather more money. As the money supply inflates, those in control of money's creation more and more concentrate their power in the society in which they issue their money, even as actual physical wealth might remain stagnant. Thus the financial sector has grown from about 5% of the economy to almost 40%, even as the living standards of average Americans and Britons has remained stagnant or fallen. We can neither fight nor hope to reform what we simply do not understand.
I'll let some former presidents close.
"All the perplexities, confusions and distresses in America arise not from defects in the Constitution or Confederation, not from want of honor or virtue, as much as from downright ignorance of the nature of coin, credit and circulation."
(John Adams, in a letter to Thomas Jefferson.)
![[livejournal.com profile]](https://www.dreamwidth.org/img/external/lj-userinfo.gif)
I cannot, though, overlook his errors. Now, before everyone rushes to the mods and reports this as a trolling post, bear in mind that he makes some very common mistakes on a subject that very few command well at all, myself especially. These mistakes are, in my opinion, directly responsible for a majority of the economic problems we are facing as a planet. Therefore, be your philosophical bent to the center, to the left, to the right; be it up to the totalitarian or down toward the anarchists; be it with Xenu or Gaia or whomever; all of us can benefit from a basic primer into the basic manner in which money today is created.
First of all, the commonly held idea. I get this from Yves Smith, an excellent money and finance blogger at Naked Capitalism. Ms. Smith spent 25 years as a banker. Let's see what she has to say about money.
Banks hold deposits and pay interest on them. Depositors have the right to demand their funds at any time, but through experience, banks know that only a small percent of the funds they hold in trust will be withdrawn on any given day, and even that might be matched or exceeded by a new inflows. Thus banks, to earn additional profit, lend out a portion of their deposits, typically $9 for every $10, at a higher interest rate than they pay to their depositors. . . .
(Yves Smith, Econned: How Unenlightened Self Interest Undermined Democracy and Corrupted Captialism, St. Martin's Press, 2010, pp. 204.)
Does that sound right? It does to most. The problem lies in some basic systemic realities. If banks hold deposits and lend at interest, where does the money to pay the interest come from? In other words, what mechanism creates the interest money added to the principal due at the close of the loan, or for that matter the depositor's interest on their savings and the bank's profits? Let's cut right to this chase. (From hereon, all emboldened words in those quoted will be my emphasis.) The Chicago Federal Reserve came out with a handy explanatory pamphlet once, which contained:
"Of course, [banks] do not really pay out loans from the money they receive as deposits. If they did this, no additional money would be created. What they do when they make loans is to accept promissory notes in exchange for credits to the borrowers' transaction accounts. Loans (assets) and deposits (liabilities) both rise [by the same amount]."
Chicago Federal Reserve, Modern Money Mechanics (1961, revised 1992).
"Credits to the borrowers' transaction account" is what most of us would call "money." Ellen Hodgson Brown maintains the banker-esque vocabulary to clarify:
When you lend someone your own money, your assets go down by the amount that the borrower's assets go up. But when a bank lends you money, its assets go up. Its liabilities also go up, since its deposits are counted as liabilities; but the money isn't really there. It is simply a liability -- something that is owed back to the depositor. The bank turns your promise to pay into an asset and a liability at the same time, balancing its books without actually transferring any pre-existing money to you.
(Ellen Hodgson Brown, Web of Debt, Third Millennium Press, 2008, p. 280, emphasis by the author.)
What Ms. Brown is trying to say is more clearly said by other authors, thankfully.
The amount of debt held by government, business and households is closely linked to the supply of money in the economy. Most of the "new" money in national economies is now created by commercial banks in the form of loans to customers.
(Tim Jackson, Prosperity Without Growth, Earthscan, 2009, pp. 25-26.)
But what of those deposits Yves Smith mentioned earlier?
Commercial banks play a dual role. They act both as "depositories" and as "banks of issue." In their role of depository, banks lend out depositors' funds (your savings and mine) to those who have need of them. That may be for either consumption or the creation of new productive capacity (capital formation). As banks of issue, they create new deposits (money) on the basis of short-term commercial bills that accompany the delivery of goods to market. That's the way it is supposed to work.
(Thomas H. Greco, Jr., The End of Money and the Future of Civilization, Chelsea Green Publishing Company, 2009, pp. 63.)
The dual role to which Mr. Greco refers is regulated by the "fractional reserve." Back to Mr. Jackson:
Governments through their central banks attempt to control how much money is created in the form of debt through two related instruments. One is the base rate -- the rate at which the central bank loans money to commercial banks. The other is the reserve requirement -- the percentage of deposits that banks are required to hold in reserve and which cannot therefore be used to make loans. The lower the base rate, the more likely commercial banks are to make loans. Over the last decade, the US Federal Reserve (and many other central banks) used an expansionary monetary policy to boost consumer spending. This worked to protect growth for a while but ultimately led to unsustainable levels of debt and destabilized the money markets. This is one of the reasons for calls to increase the reserve requirement.
(Tim Jackson, ibid., pp. 26.)
I hate to pick on otherwise excellent thinkers like Yves Smith, if only because her book EConned was (other than that quote above and a few minor quibbles) so enlightening. How could she not know of the loan creation of money? Yes, she spent 25 years as a banker; but it was as an investment banker. Investment banks are not allowed to create money through lending; only commercial or depository banks are. This is, in fact, the "firewall" in our financial system erected in the US by the Banking Act of 1933, aka the Glass–Steagall Act. Senators Glass and Steagall based this legislation on revelations into banking practice largely brought to light during the congressional hearings following the market crashes between 1929 and 1932, hearings conducted largely by Ferdinand Pecora. I've read half of the Stock Exchange Practices. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency Pursuant to S.Res. 84 and S.Res. 56 and S.Res. 97, aka the Pecora Commission Report. Once one has a background into the loaning of money into existence, it's relatively easy to pick through the banker banter and decipher the actual meaning of some of the more dangerous practices the Glass-Steagall Act prevented.
That Act, though, was largely repealed in 1999 by the Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act of 1999. It took a non-investment banker to predict what might — did — happen afterward.
[Hyman] Minsky's knowledge of banking wasn't confined to what he had read in books. For years he served as a consultant to and director of the Mark Twain Bank in St. Louis, taking a keen interest in all aspects of its business. In the traditional banking model, which dates back centuries, banks take in money from their customers and lend most of it out to businesses and other borrowers, keeping a small amount in reserve to meet depositors' demands for cash. The source of banks' profits is the "spread" between the interest rate they pay depositors and the rate they charge borrowers. In this version of banking, the banking sector's role is essentially passive: it acts as an intermediary between savers and borrowers, and its activities don't have much impact on the overall level of economic activity.
Minsky pointed out a number of deficiencies in this analysis, beginning with the fact that when a bank extends a loan it creates a very special commodity: money. When banks lend more together, the total supply of money in the economy grows, which means total spending power increases. Similarly, when banks call in loans and refuse to make new ones, the money supply contracts and overall spending power falls. Apart from the government, banks are the only institutions in the economy with the ability to create money, and that is what makes them so important.
Unfortunately, there is nothing in a banker's employment contract that says he should take into account the impact of his actions on the economy as a whole. . . . As an employee of a public company, his only obligation is to maximize profits, which involves expanding lending when he things the outlook is good and refusing to lend when he is worried about the future. But the level of bank lending that makes sense for individual banks doesn't necessarily make sense for the country.
(John Cassidy, How Markets Fail: The Logic of Economic Calamaties, Princeton University Press, 2009, pp. 210-211.)
"The level of bank lending that makes sense for individual banks" is simply the level of lending that banks can issue at interest with the most likely chance either of return . . . or of possibility to seize valuable assets obtained after default. That last is what many enamored of the gold standard don't realize, that the same system of money creation through lending was in place at that time. When the availability of gold got low, bankers simply called in their loans to be payable only in gold and waited for the defaults to lower the credit money supply. This correction hardly cost them much, since the farms and factories they repossessed more than made up for the paper losses. But I digress.
I'll return to Greco to outline the fallout of improper lending.
As pointed out earlier, the vast majority of money is created by commercial banks by the process of lending it into circulation. They have the power to make loans (issue money) on either a proper basis or an improper basis. It is not the amount of money per se that causes inflation, but the basis upon which it is created. Loans made on an improper basis have the effect of inflating the money supply. What would be an improper basis?
An improper basis is any loan that does not put goods or services into the market either immediately or in the very near term. [Here he refers to the "dual role" of banks referred above.]
In practice, however, banks these days make little distinction between these two roles and they commonly create deposits (money) by making loans to finance both the flow of goods and services into the market as well as making loans that take them out of the market. When a bank makes a loan for the purpose of financing consumer purchases [credit card debt, for example] or for investment in long-term productive assets [stocks and bonds, for example], those newly created deposits are inflationary — because they deliver goods and services to the marketplace only in the distant future, or not at all. Improper bases of issue, then, include the purchase by banks of government bonds in excess of time deposits held by savers, as well as loans that finance market speculation.
(Thomas H. Greco, Jr., ibid., pp. 63-64.)
"Finance market speculation" was exactly the lending the Glass-Steagall Act outlawed . . . until its slow erosion starting in about 1983 and eventual repeal.
Several have warned through history of this conflict of interest banks represent. Sadly, not enough do. Worse, few realize that commodity banks are legally allowed to create money almost by fiat, money that can be used to further gather more money. As the money supply inflates, those in control of money's creation more and more concentrate their power in the society in which they issue their money, even as actual physical wealth might remain stagnant. Thus the financial sector has grown from about 5% of the economy to almost 40%, even as the living standards of average Americans and Britons has remained stagnant or fallen. We can neither fight nor hope to reform what we simply do not understand.
I'll let some former presidents close.
This money trust, or, as it should be more properly called, this credit trust, of which Congress has begun an investigation, is no myth; it is no imaginary thing.
(Woodrow Wilson from his book The New Freedom.)
"All the perplexities, confusions and distresses in America arise not from defects in the Constitution or Confederation, not from want of honor or virtue, as much as from downright ignorance of the nature of coin, credit and circulation."
(John Adams, in a letter to Thomas Jefferson.)
no subject
Here's the thing. "Money" isn't "wealth". Money is an abstraction. Creation or destruction of money does not create or destroy "wealth", because "wealth" is goods and services.
The amount of money in circulation generally changes fairly slowly. so on a short timescale, the 2 are generally interchangeable, but looking at the *longer* timescale, the US$ is *constantly* losing value in real terms.
Monte's comment was about *wealth*, not money. so the mechanism by which *money* is created is relevant only insofar as it concerns the accumulation of *wealth*. For that, goods and services, must, as monte says, be created. They will be then paid for in money, and to the extent taht those that recieve that money convert it to durable assets, wealth accumulates.
While money can be freely created by the banking system, if a corresponding amount of increase in goods and services is not also created, then the additional *money* is merely inflation.
no subject
click to enlarge
no subject
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
no subject
If you brought $60 in a "basket of goods" (gold, oil, corn, rice, etcetera), from 1990 to 2010, and sold it, it would be worth $100 (assuming you are able to buy and sell at the same pricing tier, and that you didn't select cell-phones) :)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
no subject
In this market there aren't more dollars chasing less goods. In fact, after the crisis, lending has been waaaaaay down. So low inflation is exactly what you'd expect to the point that some economists worry about deflation.
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
no subject
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
no subject
no subject
While technically correct, nothing in our society prevents improperly created money from buying actual wealth. The distinction is therefore moot.
Money that can be exchanged with wealth becomes wealth. Therefore those that control the creation of money divert the wealth of the nation toward their clutches.
I used the phrase "wealth of the nation" deliberately. Consider the following:
no subject
The banking system has to be *closely* watched to prevent corruption of the system. But it's not *intrinsic* that loans only be made to the corrupt.
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
no subject
This is precisely the equivalent of claiming that, "Since nothing in our society prevents fraud from resulting in a transfer of property the distinction between theft and trade is moot."
I see that Cassidy is quick to cite Adam Smith to make the point that "reckless credit inflation is the chief cause of all economic malaise." The Austrians would agree with that point. Their own Austrian Business Cycle Theory (http://wiki.mises.org/wiki/Austrian_business_cycle_theory) explains the mechanism. The problem with Cassidy's criticism of finance is not that reckless credit creation does not cause booms and busts; it does. Rather it is his implied endorsement for credit regulation in leiu of what he considers the mistaken notion that financial markets are rational self-correcting mechanisms. His error stems from the logical contradiction of implying that where distributed entrepreneurs cannot find the "correct" rate of interest, "regulation" can somehow determine determine it. This is the fallacy of perfect equilibrium or efficent market hypothesis. (http://wiki.mises.org/wiki/Equilibrium) The Austrians point out that there is no perfect equilibrium to be found and there is no other "more efficient" correlation between differing time preferences among savers and investors, the rate of interest, to be found, outside of what the market does naturally in its very operation. It is the Federal Reserve Bank's ludicrous notion that it can guess, or worse set and determine the rate of interest which is at the root of the business cycles we experience.
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
no subject
Here's the thing. "Money" isn't "wealth". Money is an abstraction.
Money is an asset, just like goods and services. Wealth is assets minus liabilities. All you would need to do is look at a corporate balance sheet to see that. That is how money and wealth are tied together. It is not an abstraction.
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
no subject
in the definition used by economics, wealth is basically the abstraction of the value of goods and services. Money is a physical representation of the abstract value of "wealth" without the direct representation. When we converted from money being a deposit for gold, and then silver, it really did just become an abstract unit of "wealth". If you can get something you value for money, then it is wealth- as long as we continue to value money as a currency.
no subject
no subject
(no subject)
no subject
Now, oh my, where to begin? In the first place, let's start with some basics, which might possibly have saved you some work, at best. Clarifying the grounds of our debate would almost certainly have resulted in my name being taken out of the post you made. The errors you attributed to me are without substance, since you are attacking claims I did not make, although that might not be readilly apparent from what I had written in the cited material. The problem is that you have jumped to some assumptions about what I wrote that say things with which I would not agree are what I mean.
So, first off, I must tell you that I was shocked, believe me absolutely shocked to see Ellen Brown cited in a post outside of the usual economic haunts I visit. Please don't mistake that familiarity with Ms. Brown for unconditional agreement with with her, but I will clarify my positon more below. At any rate, seeing her name I must ask you: are you, in fact, familliar with Ellen Brown's full arguments and are you in agreement with her? Are you, in fact, a Greenbacker? If you are, can I have your autograph? Meeting an actual Greenbacker outside of the economic phone booth where they meet is incredible. To me, it's like seeing an actual Ku Klux Klan guy walking down my street in his robes and hood. I don't really mean to give insult by the analogy; I am referring more to the novelty of such an event more than I am to the particular distastefulness of the group's ideology. One just does't see Greenbackers anywhere. Most people don't even know what fractional reserve banking and fiat currency are, and their eyes glaze over when you try to discuss it with them. They don't understand the economics involved, are completely oblivious to the significance of the economics, and could not care less. This is unfortunate.
no subject
Still reading up on Mises and Hayek (just picked up Keynes Hayek at the library), and looking forward to Steve Keen and David Graeber (http://seattletimes.nwsource.com/html/books/2015984428_br21debt.html). Next on the library list. I'll put Rothbard on the prowl list.
no subject
Hehe don't worry about that, Musketeer-guy!
no subject
I've given your Greenbacker question more thought, and I think I am, but not as whole-heartedly as Ellen B. would probably like. There goes the trillion-dollar penny, right?
I may distill my thoughts on what preconditions I would place on Greenbacking (as well as a definition on what the heck a Greenbacker is for the econ-finance neophytes out there) in another post. I think you'll agree that the topic deserves much more discussion than just a comment reply.
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
(no subject)
no subject
To get at the root of the problem here, in sorting out the miscommunication involved in interpreting the cited comment, we would have to be clearer about the nature of money and wealth and the natures of the free market, fractional reserve banking, and fiat currency. To start,
no subject
I'll hold other commentary until I've had a chance to read something which I believe might help, Graeber's Debt: The First 5,000 Years. I heard a recent podcast that talked about its content. If those commentators are in any way correct, this might be the book for reference.
(no subject)
no subject
Repaying a loan, and thereby destroying the money, does not make you economically less powerful in the same way that making the loan, thereby expanding the money supply, made the bank more powerful.
BTW, this doesn't really drive inflation. Since the money created by banks must ultimately have some basis in the money that is provided by the governments, only the government can increase the money supply and inflation in the long term. It does this as a matter of policy to keep people from withdrawing money from the economy.
no subject
The OP and its contributors would disagree with you. Essentially, the system has evolved to allow banks to create money as long as they are overseen by their governments (to prevent historical abuses). Being a commercial bank is literally a license to print money.
(no subject)
(no subject)
no subject
no subject
Consider this quote from your post: Of course, [banks] do not really pay out loans from the money they receive as deposits.
Couldn't that just refer to the fact that depositors' balances don't mysteriously decrease when the bank makes a loan? Imagine a bank with one depositor and $1000. (Assets = liabilities = $1000.) The bank can now write a loan for $900 to a borrower, causing the bank's assets and liabilities to increase by $900. (On the asset side, this is the value of the borrower's promise to repay, on the liability side, this reflects the fact that the borrower has immediate access to $900 of the bank's money.) All of this is invisible to the original depositor, who still sees $1000 when he checks his balance at an ATM. So the money supply increases by $900. But if, between them, the depositor and the borrower demand more than $1000 of cash then the bank still needs to borrow money from someone else to make up the difference (exactly as if the loan had been made 'from the depositors' money'.)
(Or to put it another way, under a certain definition of money, you still get expansion of the money supply even if bank loans come solely from deposits.)
I don't know - maybe I misunderstood something. What do you think?
Oh, there are some very enlightening lessons on the internet, concerning banking and the nature of money in relation to wealth: see e.g. http://academicearth.org/lectures/banking-4-multiplier-effect-and-the-money-supply
no subject
Ellen Brown in her book very specifically points out that when $1000 is deposited in a land with, say, a 10% fractional reserve requirement, only $10,000 can be issued as loans. That's actually not that much, considering. The important aspect to this whole schema is that the loan be a sound one.
Let me give you another quote from another banker. (Thought about putting it in the OP, decided brevity is key.) Ellen Brown quotes this in an interview:
Here's my thoughts on this: Having the bank make the money actually strengthens the economy. Why? The banker interacts directly with the lender. Both evaluate the market value of the items the loan will buy; this puts several eyes on the purchase, if you include the seller. Through this process, the value of the money lent is kept from undo inflation, since it directly reflects the value of things in the market. It is an emergent system, a simple system that can expand to the size of a country and create benefits far beyond the simple rules that govern it.
Of course, we are in economic trouble. Why that is cannot be determined until we at least agree on the mechanism behind the economy itself. In fact, there is so little understanding and agreement on this mechanism that I suspect banks themselves put value in confusing and obfuscating the issue. It is to their benefit to hide how the sausage is made, since no one can reform what they cannot understand.